Politik und
Gesellschaft Online International Politics and Society 3/2001 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|
1994 |
1995 |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
1999 |
Jan.-Sept. 2000 |
In Israel |
70 |
60 |
58 |
74 |
107 |
116 |
124 |
In the Palestinian Authority |
325 |
343 |
342 |
364 |
387 |
415 |
444 |
Palestinian
Wage Earners in Israel |
|||||||
As percentage of total
wage earners employed in Israel |
3.5% |
2.8% |
2.6% |
3.3% |
4.7% |
4.9% |
5.0% |
As percentage of total
Palestinian wage earners |
17.7% |
14.9% |
14.6% |
17.0% |
21.6% |
21.8% |
21.8% |
This returns usbrings us back to the political
framework;,
the peace process that economic co-operationcooperation was thought to cement. Recent events
have revised our conceptions of this cement. In its present
form, it is inadequate; it easily crumbles in the absence
of the appropriate political preconditions.
Prior to the signing of the
Oslo Agreements, gross domestic product (GDP) per capita
in the West Bank and the Gaza Strip was estimated at about
$2,500 Dollar; as of 1993,
in response to the sporadic border closures, GDP per capita
fell to about $1,700 Dollar, while unemployment
rose to more than thirty per centpercent. This
trend was dramatically reversed in response to positive
economic trends, related to the altered political environment.
Hence, foreign investments, especially in 1999 and the
first half of 2000, began to flow into the region. The
rate of unemployment in the PA fell to eleven percentper centpercent, and
GDP rose by seven per centpercent, accompanied
by growth in exports to Israel and other markets, as well
as increased foreign investment. The negative impacts
that replaced these positive trends began with the outbreak
of violence.
o
Internal
impacts: According
to the latest announcement released by the Office of the
UN Special Co-ordinator,
direct losses in GDP during the first four months of restrictions
are estimated as seventy five per centpercent of
annual wages earned by Palestinian workers in Israel,
or twenty per centpercent of
projected GDP for the year 2000 assuming no border closures.
In addition, unemployment has risen to about thirty eight
percentper centpercent, or
250,000 persons, mainly because employment of Palestinian
workers in Israel effectively ceased with the border closures.
o
Balance
of PA-Israeli trade: Following the trade interruptions, losses in income from PA exports to
Israel have averaged about two million dDollars per day; the losses incurred in Israel by
the lack of exports to the PA is estimated as
threefold.
o
Miscellaneous
effects: The value
of the damages to property and infrastructure in the Palestinian Authority has been too great
to be quickly assessed. More importantly, the poverty
rate has risen from twenty one to thirty two per centpercent in
the same four-month period. Due to the high dependency
ratio in the PA, more than 900,000 people are bearing
the costs of unemployment. Similar outcomes are beginning
to be felt in Israel as well, especially in the area of
unemployment and its social consequences.
Put briefly, the PA's economy
has more or less stalled due to interruptions in both local and to cross-border economic
activity. The Palestinian
leadership should understand that it would will have to answer eventually
to its people for the severe economic price they are paying
for their political agenda.
Although the economic impacts suffered by Israel’s economy
have been less severe than those experienced in the PA,
they are nonetheless widespread, and will have long-term
repercussions for its economy. Israel’s Central Bureau
of Statistics (CBS) estimates that the country's annual
rate of economic growth in 2000, ignoring the latest events
in the West Bank and Gaza, would have been more than double
that of 1998 and 1999. The CBS has published a revised
estimate showing that in the last quarter of 2000, subsequent
to the outbreak of the Intifada El-Aqsa, growth fell by
almost ten per centpercent. This
figure is particularly dramatic if we remember that the
structural sources of Israel’s economic growth have changed
in the last decade. In the early 1990s, growth was stimulated
by rising demand based on waves of immigration from the
former Soviet Union; today, growth rests on hi-tech exports,
which are relatively immune to changes in Israel's relations
with the Palestinian Authority. The
Hhi-tech sector responds to other factors,
such as the state of local infrastructure, communications,
the general level of market stability (which has not significantly
changed), and global trends, including events in the US
stock market. The latest figures show, however, that
the hi-tech
sector cannot completely compensate for the damage
to other areas of Israel’s economy caused by political
events.
For instance, the long-term
border closures have slowed construction, which recently
began to absorb Palestinian workers once more, as well
as agricultural production. Tourism has virtually halted.
The pessimism and low morale brought on by security problems
has reduced household demand for non-basic goods like
internal tourism, entertainment, and even clothing. Local as well as
foreign investment also declined as uncertainty grew.
And, as stated, the deteriorated relations with the PA
have begun to influence Israel’s economic ties with its
trading partners, at least at the margins.
Any recommendations for reversing these
impacts should be viewed against the background of three
scenarios, each of which is motivated by the political
agendas of both sides. Our brief review will emphasizse
the economic aspects of these scenarios.
This option, involving hermetic borders
between Israel and the Palestinian Authority, has been
proposed by several political figures in Israel in response
to the Intifada El-Aqsa. It rests on a number of assumptions
that may be politically attractive but are actually economically
unreasonable. Specifically, separation involves the imposition
of strict control over the movement of labourlabor and
goods. Should this scenario be implemented, we can expect
Palestinian income per capita to decline by tens of percentpercentage points as unemployment grows and
income from taxation declines. Israel, on for its part, will be forced to import greater
numbers of wage earners from foreign countries, a move
that would reverse Palestinian reintegration into Israel's
labourlabor market
(see Table 2 and Figure 1). As Israel’s export surplus
to the West Bank and Gaza, quite sizeable in 1999 (see
Table 3), plummets, additional decline in GDP will be
felt in both entities.
|
1995 |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
1999 |
Jan.-Sept. 2000 |
Total employed |
227.6 |
245.7 |
248.8 |
235.3 |
223.8 |
221.5 |
Israelis |
144.1 |
150.5 |
146.7 |
131.4 |
120.3 |
113.1 |
Palestinians officially reported |
18.3 |
14.7 |
18.4 |
19.9 |
17.9 |
20.2 |
Palestinians not officially reported |
19.7 |
18.4 |
24.0 |
40.5 |
46.7 |
50.5 |
Wage earners from foreign countries |
45.5 |
62.1 |
59.7 |
43.5 |
38.9 |
37.7 |
|
63.3% |
61.3% |
59.0% |
55.8% |
53.8% |
51.1% |
Branch |
Sales |
Purchases |
Agriculture |
340.9 |
72.1 |
Industry and mining |
2,413.7 |
433.4 |
Electricity and water |
397.0 |
3.3 |
Construction |
178.9 |
454.3 |
Wholesale, retail and auto repair |
3,895.9 |
720.4 |
Catering and food |
3.0 |
20.6 |
Transportation, warehousing and communications |
322.6 |
120.8 |
Banking, insurance and financial services |
22.8 |
9.1 |
Real estate sales and rental |
127.0 |
61.1 |
Public services |
0.2 |
|
Education |
0.4 |
0.6 |
Health and social services |
8.3 |
13.1 |
Community and personal services |
92.3 |
7.9 |
Household services |
0.2 |
0.1 |
Total |
7,803.2 |
1,916.9 |
* NIS 4.1 = USD
1
Total separation between Israel
and the PA is not, then, an operable solution, because
of its economic toll and because of the difficulties involved
in executing the policy, especially given Israel's need
for labourlabor. Any
abatement of the security threat would also undermine
both parties' willingness to continue such a policy. In
addition, the cost of constructing a hermetic border,
estimated at two billion dollars Dollar, is too high
to be seriously considered, especially in a short- or
medium-term time frame.
This scenario reflects the status quo as well
as current perceptions of a possibly long, drawn-out period
until the tension subsides and an interim peace agreement
(at the least) is signed. Sporadic interruptions in the
movement of goods and labourlabor would
continue. Some procedural changes in the areas of tax
reimbursements or trade in agricultural goods would also
be introduced. Economic relations between the two entities
would respond immediately to political instability anticipated
prior to reaching a political solution. In the absence
of a long-term solution, this appears to be the option
most likely to be adopted at this point in time. It is
also the most appropriate for minimizsing the severe
economic damages attendant upon total separation of the
two economies. And it appears to be the most responsive
to political exigencies.
This
scenario may be the closest economic equivalent to what
has been dubbed the "New Middle East." It is
therefore intimately linked with long-term political arrangements
and a shared political agenda extending beyond the PA
and Israel to the neighbouring countries. It involves the establishment
of international administrative structures that would
promote economic co-operationcooperation in policy and practice. It provides
the preferred framework for the practical steps proposed
in this paper.
Throughout
Europe today, regional cross-border commuting has replaced
long-term migrant labourlabor as a
major input for project planning and implementation. The
history of institutionalizsed
cross-border markets, established after centuries of conflict,
provides important precedents that the Middle East might
learn from. In addition, these bottom-up initiatives, illustrate how small commercial projects,
can provide a basis for establishing co-operationcooperation at higher
levels. That is, because the projects are micro-level,
or “people-to-people” and “business-to-business,” they
offer options for solving a range of economic problems
and easing the state of unemployment relatively quickly.
In policy terms, this means that some forms of co-operatcooperative economic
activity, dependent on administrative mechanisms (including
arrangements for capital mobility), can be established
between neighboring countries independently of higher-level
political solutions. Stated differently, political conditions
need not automatically interfere with mutually beneficial
economic relations.
Indications of the approach's
feasibility are already available. We need only cite joint
ventures, such as those begun at the Erez Border Crossing,
as well as labourlabor statistics.
The latter especially indicate that Israelis and Palestinians
have found ways to side step both bureaucratic and political
obstacles for years. For example, the number of Palestinians
employed in the construction sector who were not officially
reported has always been greater than the number officially
reported, and these numbers have consistently grown (see
Table 4). During the first nine months of 2000, only about
one-third of the 70,000 Palestinians working in construction
were registered. This trend has held despite the border
closures (see Table 5). The data indicate that small-scale,
private ventures can solve some labourlabor market
problems existing in both the PA and in Israel. They also
indicate that under conditions of normalization, the flow
of black market labourlabor would
more or less cease. All Palestinian workers could then
begin to enjoy the legislated social and economic benefits
as well as the legal protection that are unavailable to
them under present conditions.
|
1995 |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
1999 |
Jan.-Sept. 2000 |
Total employed in branch |
77.9 |
78.5 |
78.5 |
82.7 |
83.6 |
81.0 |
Israelis |
56.8 |
50.4 |
48.2 |
47.5 |
49.6 |
47.1 |
Wage earners from foreign countries |
15.1 |
22.0 |
22.5 |
24.1 |
24.0 |
23.4 |
Palestinians working with permits |
5.7 |
4.1 |
5.3 |
6.4 |
6.5 |
6.3 |
Palestinians working without permits |
0.3 |
2.0 |
2.5 |
4.7 |
3.5 |
4.2 |
|
7.7% |
7.8% |
9.9% |
13.4% |
12.0% |
13.0% |
Year |
West Bank |
Gaza |
1993 |
17 |
26 |
1994 |
64 |
76 |
1995 |
80 |
102 |
1996 |
90 |
138 |
1997 |
57 |
70 |
1998 |
14 |
48 |
1999 (First half) |
6 |
6 |
Before turning to our suggestions
for putting co-operationcooperation into practice, we should comment
on the respective time span. Previous expectations regarding
the realization of many economic projects were unrealistic.
That is, many of the economic outcomes of Oslo anticipated
by Israelis could not materialize in the absence of lower-level
co-operatcooperative mechanisms.
Thus, the suggestions we offer are keyed to what we consider
to be the appropriate temporal dimension in order to avoid
delusions related to their applicability.
Visual support for the linkage between political expectations and economic programs can be found in Figure 2. Here we see three curves, two of which represent forecasts, the third the facts. As we can see, by 1996 the PA began experiencing real growth in income per capita; the current violence has abruptly halted this trend. What is enlightening for those interested in planning practical projects is the gap between the pessimistic forecast (equivalent to the total severance scenario) and the de facto growth rate. First, we should remember that forecasts are just that, based on assumptions that are often proved irrelevant in reality. Second, de-facto growth reflects unanticipated real events. In the present case, the forecasts were based on assumptions resting on the Oslo Agreements; the de-facto growth resulted from attempts to translate that atmosphere into economic behavior. Specifically, Oslo stimulated attempts to develop the Palestinian economy independently of Israel. This meant that foreign capital was invited and began to flow to the PA, but not at a level that could have been reached if Israeli investors had been included. Major projects initiated were long-term in character and required investment and planning resources beyond those available to the PA. Reaping the fruits of these projects was therefore delayed.
The main objective of any
short-term economic policy under present circumstances
is to ease the severe economic distress experienced by
the Palestinian population and modify (i.e., halt if not
reverse) the negative trends appearing in Israel. As indicated,
this requires, first and foremost, acceptance of the fact
that the two economies will remain interdependent irrespective
of political developments.
The most critical problem
is unemployment. Job creation should be targeted at the
PA itself. Projects would should entail small-scale
investments or transfers of support to established businesses
in danger of folding or, alternatively,
to those displaying growth potential. A quick glance
at the Erez border crossing, whose warehouses are clogged
with Palestinian goods awaiting shipment to Israel, indicates
the potential of such commercial projects. Measures such
as boycotting Israeli products should be avoided for their
destructive impact on commercial normalization.
Second, border restrictions
on the movement of labourlabor are toshould be eased. In addition
to renewing access to sources of direct income to Palestinian
families, this move would re-institute
the flow of taxes reimbursed by Israel to the PA, funds
that significantly contribute to the PA’s administrative
budget. These steps should be supported by Palestinian
authorities in order to restore the minimumal confidence required for labourlabor market
co-operationcooperation. In tandem, the number of work permits
issued to Palestinians seeking employment in Israel should
be greatly increased, together with the possibility of
allowing more workers to remain in Israel overnight. From
Israel’s point of view, such a policy would reduce the
nation’s dependence on wage earners coming from countries
beyond the Middle Eastern region.
Wage considerations should
also play a part in reviving the cross-border movement
of labourlabor. Because Unfortunately, as the wage
gap will unfortunately
continue for some time, the hiring of
Palestinian workers continues to be a basic tool for reducing
the wage costs of Israeli manufacturing. This implies
that Israel is the PA’s most accessible supplier of services,
such as occupational and management training. Short-term
training projects should be devised to meet immediate
as well as medium-range needs.
Obviously, the willingness
of private Israeli interests to invest in projects in
the PA has diminished considerably since the latest outbreak
of violence. Hence, the Palestinians will have to turn
to institutional bodies, major corporations, NGOs,
and government agencies in Israel and abroad, with requests
to develop operable programs of capital investment in
the PA and channel the requisite funds.
One promising suggestion,
based on available institutional resources, could be the
creation of a UN-sponsored “International Emergency Forum.”
Members of this forum would include,
among others, the PA, Israel, the US, and the European
Union., among others. This forum would operate
as a think tank and investment clearing house: It would
propose programs and, at the same time, arrange the financing
for them. Because ofDue to its access to information,
the forum could more easily co-ordinate projects more easily and ensure maximum efficiency of
resource allocation. It could also lobby for projects
favored by the Palestinians. With both Israelis and Palestinians
participating, this forum could help introduce uniformity
into the standards and tools of proper administration
which, in addition to co-operationcooperation, is needed for effective
governance. in addition to
co-operation.
Another route entails making
foreign markets accessible to Palestinian exports, particularly
agricultural products. Although this demands the co-operationcooperation of governments
in the area of trade and tariffs, a reasonable level of
co-ordination could be achieved in the medium term. Nevertheless,
such a policy has limitations: Just how receptive European
markets are to penetration by the current range of Palestinian
goods, including agricultural produce, must be thoroughly
investigated. In the Far East, there may be too much local
competition for Palestinian manufactured goods. Export
targets in the Middle East and Africa are problematic:
Income per capita in these nations is lower than that
in the PA, which means that these markets have little
potential to absorb Palestinian goods. Therefore, they
can provide few stimuli to Palestinian industrial development.
This leaves Israel as the most “natural” market for Palestinian
exports, a fact that emphasizes the negative effects of
commercial embargoes.
Obviously, long-term economic
co-operationcooperation can be maintained only if the participants
view themselves as fully-fledged partners. This requires upgrading
the economic capacities of the "junior" partner.
Therefore, in order to achieve long-term results, the
development of the PA’s infrastructure must be accelerated
now, especially those civil engineering projects already
on the drawing board. It is true that infrastructure projects
supply little short-term respite from unemployment because
of the long time frame in which they are realized, but
they are unavoidable. Not least important is the respite
from the hardships of daily life that only water, sewage,
electrification, communications, and transportation projects
can provide. The choice of projects should depend, in
part, on how quickly they can be executed and how much
manpower is needed. In the background lies the need to
inject huge amounts of international development capital, - a
project that Israel could actively support.
My
concluding remarks return us to the political issues that
provide the framework for our list of practical suggestions
geared toward economic co-operationcooperation. The long-term
solution to economic development that I foresee is the
most problematic: I firmly believe that a Palestinian
state is the necessary response to many of the economic
problems besetting both the PA and Israel. This is based
on the view, shared by many economists as well as politicians
in Israel, that there is no alternative to a political
solution for either party. In order for regional co-operationcooperation and development to progress, formal
institutions that can set agendas, recruit resources, and guarantee policy
implementation are required. We need laws, courts, tax
authorities, border control and inspection, health services,
administrative as well as planning agencies. Only sovereign
states can make it possible to turn economic interdependence
into an equitable, shared destiny.